Part 9 - Ch 16 Financial Distress, Managerial Incentives, and Information
14-05-2024
16.1 Default and Bankruptcy in a Perfect Market
16.2 The Costs of Bankruptcy and Financial Distress
16.3 Financial Distress Costs and Firm Value
16.4 Optimal Capital Structure: The Tradeoff Theory
16.5 Exploiting Debt Holders: The Agency Costs of Leverage
16.6 Motivating Managers: The Agency Benefits of Leverage
16.7 Agency Costs and the Tradeoff Theory
16.8 Asymmetric Information and Capital Structure
16.9 Capital Structure: The Bottom Line
An important consequence of leverage is the risk of bankruptcy.
Equity financing does not carry this risk.
Although equity holders hope to receive dividends, the firm is not legally obligated to pay them.
Financial Distress
Default
When a firm fails to make the required interest or principal payments on its debt or violates a debt covenant (see next slide).
After the firm defaults, debt holders are given certain rights to the assets of the firm and may even take legal ownership of the firm’s assets through bankruptcy.
Debt covenants are restrictions that lenders (creditors, debt holders, investors) put on lending agreements to limit the actions of the borrower (debtor).
In other words, debt covenants are agreements between a company and its lenders that the company will operate within certain rules set by the lenders.
They are also called banking covenants or financial covenants.
When a debt covenant is violated, depending on the severity, the lender can do several things:
Positive debt covenants are covenants that state what the borrower must do.
Negative debt covenants are covenants that state what the borrower cannot do.
Example
Let’s discuss an example of default.
Armin is considering a new project.
Armin may employ one of two alternative capital structures:
Without Lev. | Without Lev. | With Lev. | With Lev. | |
---|---|---|---|---|
Success | Failure | Success | Failure | |
Debt Value | - | - | 100 | 80 |
Equity value | 150 | 80 | 50 | 0 |
All investors | 150 | 80 | 150 | 80 |
Both debt and equity holders are worse off if the product fails rather than succeeds.
The firm is in default if the project fails with leverage.
Note, the decline in value is not caused by bankruptcy:
The decline is the same whether or not the firm has leverage.
The takeaway of first subsection is:
With perfect capital markets, Modigliani-Miller (MM) Proposition I applies: The total value to all investors does not depend on the firm’s capital structure.
Problem
Consider the following outcomes for the following scenarios both with and without leverage for Moon Industries’ new venture:
Without Lev. | Without Lev. | With Lev. | With Lev. | |
---|---|---|---|---|
Success | Failure | Success | Failure | |
Debt Value | - | - | 150 | 90 |
Equity value | 250 | 90 | 100 | 0 |
All investors | 250 | 90 | 250 | 90 |
Problem
\[V^U = \frac{0.5 \times 250 + 0.5 \times 90}{1.04} = 163.46 million\]
\[V^L = \frac{0.5 \times 100 + 0.5 \times 0}{1.04} = 48.08 million\]
\[Debt = \frac{0.5 \times 150 + 0.5 \times 90}{1.04} = 115.38 million\] \[V^L + Debt = 48.08 million + 115.38 million = 163.46 million\]
With perfect capital markets, the risk of bankruptcy is not a disadvantage of debt; rather, bankruptcy shifts the ownership of the firm from equity holders to debt holders without changing the total value available to all investors (this is basically the previous section).
In reality, the bankruptcy process is complex, time-consuming, and costly.
Costly outside experts are often hired by the firm to assist with the bankruptcy.
Creditors also incur similar costs during the bankruptcy process.
The direct costs of bankruptcy reduce the value of the assets that the firm’s investors will ultimately receive.
Although the indirect costs are difficult to measure accurately, they are often much larger than the direct costs of bankruptcy.
It is estimated that the potential loss due to financial distress is 10% to 20% of firm value.
Remember previous example
Remember previous example
Assuming financial distress costs of 20 million.
That is, the total value to all investors is now less with leverage than it is without leverage when the new product fails.
Without Lev. | Without Lev. | With Lev. | With Lev. | |
---|---|---|---|---|
Success | Failure | Success | Failure | |
Debt Value | - | - | 100 | 60 |
Equity value | 150 | 80 | 50 | 0 |
All investors | 150 | 80 | 150 | 60 |
Problem
Extending the previous example, assume now that the costs of financial distress are $15 million:
Without Lev. | Without Lev. | With Lev. | With Lev. | |
---|---|---|---|---|
Success | Failure | Success | Failure | |
Debt Value | - | - | 150 | 75 |
Equity value | 250 | 90 | 100 | 0 |
All investors | 250 | 90 | 250 | 75 |
Problem
\[V^U = \frac{0.5 \times 250 + 0.5 \times 90}{1.04} = 163.46 million\]
\[V^L = \frac{0.5 \times 100 + 0.5 \times 0}{1.04} = 48.08 million\]
\[Debt = \frac{0.5 \times 150 + 0.5 \times 75}{1.04} = 108.17 million\]
\[V^L + Debt = 48.08 million + 108.17 million = 156.25 million\]
The difference, (\(163.46 − 156.25 = 7.21\)), is the present value of the 15 million in financial distress costs
\[PV(FDC) = \frac{0.5\times 0 + 0.5 \times 15}{1.04} = 7.21\]
Who Pays for Financial Distress Costs?
When securities are fairly priced, the original shareholders of a firm pay the present value of the costs associated with bankruptcy and financial distress.
Tradeoff Theory
The firm picks its capital structure by trading off the benefits of the tax shield from debt against the costs of financial distress and agency costs.
According to the Tradeoff theory, the total value of a levered firm equals the value of the firm without leverage plus the present value of the tax savings from debt, less the present value of financial distress costs:
\[V^L = V^U + PV(Interest\;tax\;shield) - PV(Financial\;distress\;costs)\]
Three key factors determine the present value of financial distress costs:
1) The probability of financial distress
2) The magnitude of the costs after a firm is in distress
3) The appropriate discount rate for the distress costs
It is easy to see that each firm will have an optimal leverage level
The Tradeoff theory states that firms should increase their leverage until it reaches the level for which the firm value is maximized. At this point, the tax savings that result from increasing leverage are perfectly offset by the increased probability of incurring the costs of financial distress.
Problem
Holland, Inc. is considering adding leverage to its capital structure. Holland’s managers believe they can add as much as 50 million in debt and exploit the benefits of the tax shield. They estimate \(T_c = 39\%\). However, they also recognize that higher debt increases the risk of financial distress. Based on simulations of the firm’s future cash flows, the CFO has made the following estimates (in millions of dollars):
Debt | 0 | 10 | 20 | 30 | 40 | 50 |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
PV(Int. Tax. Shield) | 0 | 3.9 | 7.8 | 11.7 | 15.6 | 19.5 |
PV(Fin. Dis. Costs) | 0 | 0 | 0 | 3.38 | 19.23 | 23.47 |
Net Benefit | 0 | 3.9 | 7.8 | 8.32 | -3.63 | -3.97 |
The level of debt that leads to the highest net benefit is 30 million. Holland will gain 11.7 million due to tax shields and lose 3.38 million due to the present value of financial distress costs, for a net gain of 8.32 million.
Agency Costs
Consider Baxter, Inc., which is facing financial distress
Baxter is considering a new strategy
Should Baxter execute this strategy?
Certainly not!
The expected value of the firm’s assets under the new strategy is 800,000, a decline of 100,000 from the old strategy
\[50\% \times 1.3 million + 50\% \times 0,3 million = 0,8 million\]
However, despite the negative expected payoff, some within the firm have suggested that Baxter should go ahead with the new strategy
Can shareholders benefit from this decision? What would be the rationale?
If Baxter does nothing, it will ultimately default and equity holders will get nothing with certainty.
\[50\% \times 0 + 50\% \times 300.000 = 150.000\]
Old Strat. | New Success | New failure | New Expected | |
---|---|---|---|---|
Value of assets | 900 | 1300 | 300 | 800 |
Debt | 900 | 1000 | 300 | 650 |
Equity | 0 | 300 | 0 | 150 |
Asset Substitution Problem
Debt Overhang and Under-Investment
Now assume Baxter does not pursue the risky strategy, but instead the firm is considering an investment opportunity that requires an initial investment of $100,000 and will generate a risk-free return of 50%.
If the current risk-free rate is 5%, this investment clearly has a positive NPV.
Debt Overhang and Under-Investment
Without project | With new project | |
---|---|---|
Existing assets | 900 | 900 |
New project | 150 | |
Total firm value | 900 | 1050 |
Debt | 900 | 1000 |
Equity | 0 | 50 |
Debt Overhang and Under-Investment
A situation in which equity holders choose not to invest in a positive NPV project because the firm is in financial distress and the value of undertaking the investment opportunity will accrue to bondholders rather than themselves.
When a firm faces financial distress, it may choose not to finance new, positive-NPV projects.
Cashing Out
When a firm faces financial distress, shareholders have an incentive to withdraw money from the firm, if possible.
For example, if it is likely the company will default, the firm may sell assets below market value and use the funds to pay an immediate cash dividend to the shareholders.
These are examples of Agency costs of Leverage
Leverage can encourage managers and shareholders to act in ways that reduce value.
Management Entrenchment
Entrenchment may allow managers to run the firm in their own best interests, rather than in the best interests of the shareholders. For instance, spending on perks.
Leverage can reduce the degree of managerial entrenchment because managers are more likely to be fired when a firm faces financial distress.
Concentration of Ownership
Concentration of Ownership
Reduction of Wasteful Investment
Managerial Overconfidence
Free Cash Flow Hypothesis
The takeaway of this section is:
Leverage also has benefits that might increase firm value.
The net effect is an empirical matter and is not trivial to find.
Firms would pursue an optimal debt level.
We can now write that:
\[V^L = V^U + PV(Interest\;tax\;shield) - PV(Financial\;distress\;costs)\] \[- PV(Agency\;costs\;of\;debt) + PV(Agency\;benefits\;of\;debt)\]
The Optimal Debt Level
Again, the optimal level is not the same to all firms.
R&D-Intensive Firms
Low-Growth, Mature Firms
Asymmetric Information
Signaling Theory of Debt
Adverse Selection : The idea that when the buyers and sellers have different information, the average quality of assets in the market will differ from the average quality overall.
Lemons Principle
When a seller has private information about the value of a good, buyers will discount the price they are willing to pay due to adverse selection.
An example of adverse selection and the lemons principle is the used car market.
If the seller has private information about the quality of the car, then her desire to sell reveals the car is probably of low quality.
Buyers are therefore reluctant to buy except at heavily discounted prices.
Owners of high-quality cars are reluctant to sell because they know buyers will think they are selling a lemon and offer only a low price.
Consequently, the quality and prices of cars sold in the market are both low.
This same principle can be applied to the market for equity.
In other words,
If the firm is issuing equity at market prices, it must be that managers think the stock is expensive.
If the firm is buying back shares at market prices, it must be that managers think the stock is cheap.
Problem
You are an analyst who follows Great Windows’ stock. Although the current stock price is 37.50, you believe the stock is worth either 25 or 50, depending on the success of a new product launch.
If Great Windows’ CEO announces that she plans to buy 10,000 additional shares in the company, how will the share price change?
Solution
If the CEO knows the new product launch is a failure, she would sell the stock at 37.50 given that the she knows true value is 25.
If the CEO announces that she is buying 10,000 additional shares, she must know that the new product launch is a success and the true value is 50 per share. Thus, the stock price should rise to 50.
The Pecking Order of Financing Choices
Problem
Nesbat Industries needs to raise 25 million for a new investment project. If the firm issues one year debt, it may have to pay an interest rate of 10%, although Nesbat’s managers believe that 8% would be a fair rate given the level of risk.
However, if the firm issues equity, they believe the equity may be underpriced by 7.5%.
What is the cost to current shareholders of financing the project out of retained earnings, debt, and equity?
Solution
With perfect capital markets, a firm’s security choice alters the risk of the firm’s equity, but it does not change its value or the amount it can raise from outside investors
The optimal capital structure depends on market imperfections, such as taxes, financial distress costs, agency costs, and asymmetric information.
Financial distress may lead to other consequences that reduce the value of the firm
Agency costs and benefits of leverage are also important determinants of capital structure.
A firm must also consider the potential signaling and adverse selection consequences of its financing choice
Actively changing a firm’s capital structure entails transactions costs.
Remember to solve:
QUESTIONS?
Henrique C. Martins
[Henrique C. Martins] [henrique.martins@fgv.br] [Teaching Resources] [Practice T/F & Numeric] [Interact][Do not use without permission]