Part 7 - Ch 14 Capital Structure in a Perfect Market
07-05-2024
14.1 Equity Versus Debt Financing
14.2 MM I: Leverage, Arbitrage, and Firm Value
14.3 MM II: Leverage, Risk, and the Cost of Capital
14.4 Capital Structure Fallacies
14.5 MM: Beyond the Propositions
When corporations raise funds from outside investors, they must choose which type of security to issue.
The most common choices are financing through equity alone and financing through a combination of debt and equity.
The relative proportions of debt, equity, and other securities that a firm has outstanding constitute its capital structure.
A central question in this chapter:
If a firm decides for a specific capital structure, does it change the investment decisions?
Similarly,
Do capital structure decisions affect firm value?
For clarity: Throughout the chapter, we will assume the firm is a portfolio of debt and equity (and maybe other securities).
Let’s start our discussion by analyzing again the value of a firm.
Imagine an economy with two future states; firm will receive cash flows as follows:
Date 0 (investment) | Date 1 (strong economy) | Date 1 (Weak economy) |
---|---|---|
-800 | 1400 | 900 |
The cost of capital for this project is 15%. Each scenario has a 50% probability of occurrence. The NPV is:
\[NPV = -800 + \frac{\frac{1}{2} \times 1400 + \frac{1}{2} \times 900 }{1.15} = 200\]
\[PV(CF) = \frac{1150}{1.15} = 1000\]
So the firm value today is $1000. If the firm wants to finance the project all-equity, it could raise this amount selling equity. In this case, the firm is unlevered equity.
The expected return on the unlevered equity is 15%.
Date 0 (investment) | Date 1 (strong economy) | Date 1 (Weak economy) |
---|---|---|
1000 | 1400 | 900 |
Return | +40% | -10% |
\[\frac{1}{2} \times 40\% + \frac{1}{2} \times -10\% = 15\%\]
Let’s now analyse the case where the firm issues 500 of debt and 500 of equity. This firm is levered equity. The debt cost is 5%. Do the NPV and the firm value change?
Because the firm needs to pay debt holders no matter the state of the economy, we can say that Debt value in Date 1 is 525 (\(500 \times 1.05\)).
Because we know the firm value in each state of the economy, we can say that the difference between the firm value and the debt value is the equity value: \(V - D = E\), i.e. \(1400 - 525 = 875\) or \(900 - 525 = 375\).
Then, we can write:
Source | Date 0 (investment) | Date 1 (strong economy) | Date 1 (Weak economy) |
---|---|---|---|
Debt (D) | 500 | 525 | 525 |
Equity (E) | ? | 875 | 375 |
Firm (V) | 1000 | 1400 | 900 |
Wait, but if debt cost is only 5%, why the firm value still is 1.000? Shouldn’t the value of equity increase?
The answer is that the cost of equity increases for levered equity. Let’s see how.
Source | Date 0 (investment) | Date 1 (strong) | Date 1 (Weak) | Return 1 (strong) | Return 1 (Weak) |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
D | 500 | 525 | 525 | 5% | 5% |
E | 500 | 875 | 375 | 75% | -25% |
V | 1000 | 1400 | 900 | 40% | -10% |
Unlevered equity has returns of 40% or -10%. On average, 15%.
Debt has return of 5% no matter what.
Levered equity has returns of 75% (\(\frac{875}{500}-1\)) or -25% (\(\frac{375}{500}-1\)). On average, 25%.
The takeaway:
Levered equity is riskier, so the cost of capital is higher.
Source | Return sensitivity (systematic risk) | Risk premium |
---|---|---|
Debt | 5% - 5% = 0% | 5% - 5% = 0% |
Unlevered Equity | 40% - (-10%) = 50% | 15% - 5% = 10% |
Levered Equity | 75% - (-25%) = 100% | 25% - 5% = 20% |
Because the debt’s return bears no systematic risk, its risk premium is zero.
In this particular case, the levered equity has twice the systematic risk of the unlevered equity and, as a result, has twice the risk premium.
Modigliani and Miller argued that with perfect capital markets, the total value of a firm should not depend on its capital structure.
In summary
Problem
Using the same values as before, suppose the firm borrows $700 when financing the project.
According to Modigliani and Miller, what should the value of the equity be? What is the expected return?
Because the value of the firm’s total cash flows is still 1000, if the firm borrows 700, its equity will be worth 300.
The firm will owe 700 × 1.05 = 735 in one year to debt holders. Thus,
Expected return is:
\[\frac{1}{2} \times 121.67\% + \frac{1}{2} \times -45\% = 38.33\%\]
Note that the equity has a return sensitivity of 121.67% − (−45.0%) = 166.67%.
Its risk premium is 38.33% − 5% = 33.33%.
Source | Date 0 | Date 1 (strong) | Date 1 (Weak) | Ret. 1 (strong) | Ret. 1 (Weak) | Syst. risk | Risk premium |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Debt | 700 | 735 | 735 | 5% | 5% | 5% - 5% = 0% | 5% - 5% = 0% |
Equity | 300 | 665 | 165 | 122% | -45% | 122% - (-45%) = 167% | 38% - 5% = 33% |
Firm | 1000 | 1400 | 900 | 40% | -10% | 75% - (-25%) = 100% | 25% - 5% = 20% |
So, debt increases equity risk.
In this subsection, we will explore further the MM propositions and the theory of capital structure.
First, we will understand what Homemade Leverage means.
Assume the firm is an all−equity firm. An investor who would prefer to hold levered equity can do so by using leverage in his own portfolio.
Source | Date 0 | Date 1 (strong economy) | Date 1 (Weak economy) |
---|---|---|---|
Unlevered equity (firm) | 1000 | 1400 | 900 |
Margin loan (Investor borrowing) | -500 | -525 | -525 |
Levered equity (Investor’s return) | 500 | 875 | 375 |
If the cash flows of the unlevered equity serve as collateral for the margin loan (at the risk−free rate of 5%), then by using homemade leverage, the investor has replicated the payoffs to the levered equity.
Now assume the firm uses debt, but the investor would prefer to hold unlevered equity.
The investor can replicate the payoffs of unlevered equity by buying both the debt and the equity of the firm.
Combining the cash flows of the two securities produces cash flows identical to unlevered equity, for a total cost of $1000.
Source | Date 0 | Date 1 (strong economy) | Date 1 (Weak economy) |
---|---|---|---|
Debt (Investor’s lending) | 500 | 525 | 525 |
Levered equity (the firm) | 500 | 875 | 375 |
Unlevered equity (Investor’s return) | 1000 | 1400 | 900 |
Homemade leverage
In each case, the firm’s choice of capital structure does not affect the opportunities available to investors.
Investors can alter the leverage choice of the firm to suit their personal tastes either by adding more leverage or by reducing leverage.
With perfect capital markets, different choices of capital structure offer no benefit to investors and does not affect the value of the firm.
In summary,
Modigliani and Miller (or simply MM) showed that leverage would not affect the total value of the firm.
This result holds more generally under a set of conditions referred to as perfect capital markets:
Under these conditions, MM demonstrated the following result regarding the role of capital structure in determining firm value:
MM Proposition I: In a perfect capital market, the total value of a firm’s securities is equal to the market value of the total cash flows generated by its assets and is not affected by its choice of capital structure.
In the absence of taxes or other transaction costs, the total cash flow paid out to all of a firm’s security holders is equal to the total cash flow generated by the firm’s assets.
Modigliani and Miller showed that a firm’s financing choice does not affect its value. But how can we reconcile this conclusion with the fact that the cost of capital differs for different securities?
We will now discuss the second proposition of MM.
MM’s first proposition can be used to derive an explicit relationship between leverage and the equity cost of capital. Let’s denote:
MMI states that:
\[E+D = U = A\]
That is, the total market value of the firm’s securities is equal to the market value of its assets, whether the firm is unlevered or levered.
Also, remember that the return of a portfolio is the weighted average of the returns.
So, we can write that the return on unlevered equity (\(R_u\)) is related to the returns of levered equity (\(R_e\)) and debt (\(R_d\)):
\[R_u = \frac{E}{E+D} \times R_e + \frac{D}{E+D} \times R_d\] Solving for \(R_e\):
\[R_e = R_u + \frac{D}{E} \times (R_u - R_d)\]
That is, the levered equity return equals the unlevered return, plus a premium due to leverage. The amount of the premium depends on the amount of leverage, measured by the firm’s market value debt−equity ratio.
Proposition II: The cost of capital of levered equity is equal to the cost of capital of unlevered equity plus a premium that is proportional to the market value debt−equity ratio.
Using the previous example’s numbers:
Problem
Suppose the entrepreneur borrows only $700 when financing the project. Recall that the expected return on unlevered equity is 15% and the risk−free rate is 5%. According to MM Proposition II, what will be the firm’s equity cost of capital?
\[R_e = R_u + \frac{D}{E} \times (R_u - R_d) = 15\% + \frac{700}{300} \times (15\%-5\%) = 38.33\%\]
Exactly the same cost we found before.
We can use the insight of Modigliani and Miller to understand the effect of leverage on the firm’s cost of capital for new investments.
If a firm is unlevered, all of the free cash flows generated by its assets are paid out to its equity holders.
\[R_u = R_a\]
If a firm is levered, project \(R_A\) is equal to the firm’s weighted average cost of capital.
\[R_{wacc} = R_u = R_a\]
That is, with perfect capital markets, a firm’s WACC is independent of its capital structure and is equal to its equity cost of capital if it is unlevered, which matches the cost of capital of its assets.
Assuming taxes do not exist:
The takeaway:
Although debt has a lower cost of capital than equity, leverage does not lower a firm’s WACC. As a result, the value of the firm’s free cash flow evaluated using the WACC does not change, and so the enterprise value of the firm does not depend on its financing choices.
Problem
Honeywell International Inc. (HON) has a market debt−equity ratio of 0.5.
Assume its current debt cost of capital is 6.5%, and its equity cost of capital is 14%.
If HON issues equity and uses the proceeds to repay its debt and reduce its debt−equity ratio to 0.4, it will lower its debt cost of capital to 5.75%.
With perfect capital markets, what effect will this transaction have on HON’s equity cost of capital and WACC?
Current WACC
\[R_{wacc} = \frac{E}{E+D} \times R_e + \frac{D}{E+D} \times R_d = \frac{2}{2+1} \times 14 + \frac{1}{2+1} \times 6.5 = 11.5\%\]
New Cost of Equity:
\[R_e = R_u + \frac{D}{E} (R_u - R_a) = 11.5 +0.4 \times (11.5 - 5.75) = 13.8\%\]
“New” WACC:
\[R_{wacc_{new}} = \frac{1}{1+0.4} \times 13.8 + \frac{0.4}{1+0.4} \times 5.75 = 11.5\%\]
If the firm’s capital structure is made up of multiple securities, then the WACC is calculated by computing the weighted average cost of capital of all of the firm’s securities.
Let’s say the firm has Equity (E), Debt (D), Warrant (W) issued:
\[R_{wacc} = R_u = R_e \times \frac{E}{E+D+W} + R_d \times \frac{D}{E+D+W} + R_w \times \frac{W}{E+D+W} \]
Remember that
\[\beta_u = \frac{E}{D+E} \times \beta_e + \frac{D}{D+E} \times \beta_d\]
When a firm changes its capital structure without changing its investments, its unlevered beta will remain unaltered. However, its equity beta will change to reflect the effect of the capital structure change on its risk.
\[\beta_e = \beta_u + \frac{D}{E} (\beta_u - \beta_d)\]
Obs
Problem
In August 2018, Reenor had a market capitalization of 140 billion. It had debt of 25.4 billion as well as cash and short−term investments of 60.4 billion. Its equity beta was 1.09 and its debt beta was approximately zero. What was Reenor’s enterprise value at time? Given a risk−free rate of 2% and a market risk premium of 5%, estimate the unlevered cost of capital of Reenor’s business.
Reenor’s net debt = 25.4 − 60.4 billion = −35.0 billion. Enterprise value 140 billion − 35billion = 105 billion.
\[\beta_u = \frac{E}{E+D} \times \beta_e + \frac{D}{E+D} \times \beta_d = \frac{140}{105} \times 1.09 + \frac{-35}{105} \times 0 = 1.45\] Unlevered cost of capital:
\[R_u = 2\% + 1.45 \times 5\% = 9.25\%\]
We will discuss now two fallacies concerning capital structure:
Leverage and EPS example
Suppose LVI has no debt. Because there is no interest and no taxes, LVI’s earnings would equal its EBIT and LVI’s earnings per share without leverage would be
\[EPS=\frac{earnings}{Out. Shares}=\frac{10\;million}{10\;million}= 1\]
\[EPS=\frac{earnings}{Out. Shares}=\frac{8.8\;million}{8\;million}= 1.1\] EPS increases. Should firm value increase?
The answer is no.
Just like equity becomes riskier when the firm issues debt, the earnings stream is also riskier when the firm issues debt.
(no debt) | (with debt) | |
---|---|---|
EBIT | 10 | 10 |
- Interets | 0 | 1.2 |
Earnings | 10 | 8.8 |
# shares (out) | 10 | 10 |
EPS | 1 | 1.1 |
No debt
EBIT | 0 | 2 | 4 | 6 | 8 | 10 | 12 | 14 | 16 | 18 | 20 |
- Int. | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 |
Earnings | 0 | 2 | 4 | 6 | 8 | 10 | 12 | 14 | 16 | 18 | 20 |
# shares | 10 | 10 | 10 | 10 | 10 | 10 | 10 | 10 | 10 | 10 | 10 |
EPS | 0 | 0.2 | 0.4 | 0.6 | 0.8 | 1 | 1.2 | 1.4 | 1.6 | 1.8 | 2.0 |
With debt
EBIT | 0 | 2 | 4 | 6 | 8 | 10 | 12 | 14 | 16 | 18 | 20 |
- Int. | 1.2 | 1.2 | 1.2 | 1.2 | 1.2 | 1.2 | 1.2 | 1.2 | 1.2 | 1.2 | 1.2 |
Earnings | -1.2 | 0.8 | 2.8 | 4.8 | 6.8 | 8.8 | 10.8 | 12.8 | 14.8 | 16.8 | 18.8 |
# shares | 10 | 10 | 10 | 10 | 10 | 10 | 10 | 10 | 10 | 10 | 10 |
EPS | -0.12 | 0.08 | 0.28 | 0.48 | 0.68 | 0.88 | 1.08 | 1.28 | 1.48 | 1.68 | 1.88 |
Problem
Assume that LVI’s EBIT is not expected to grow in the future and that all earnings are paid as dividends. Use MM proposition I and II to show that the increase in expected EPS for LVI will not lead to an increase in the share price.
Solution
Without leverage, expected earnings per share and therefore dividends are 1 each year, and the share price 7.50. Let r be LVI’s cost of capital without leverage. Then we can value LVI as a perpetuity:
\[P = 7.50 = \frac{Div}{R_u} = \frac{EPS}{R_u} = \frac{1}{R_u}\]
Therefore, current stock price implies that \(R_u = \frac{1}{7.50} = 13.33\%\)
After the transaction, \(\frac{D}{E} = \frac{1}{4}\), thus, we can write:
\[R_e= R_u +\frac{D}{E} \times (R_u - R_d) = 13.33 + 0.25 \times (13.33 - 8) = 14.66\]
Given that expected EPS is now 1.10 per share, the new value of the shares equals
\[P=\frac{1.10}{14.66} = 7.50\]
Thus, even though EPS is higher, due to the additional risk, shareholders will demand a higher return. These effects cancel out, so the price per share is unchanged.
Because the firm’s earnings per share and price-earnings ratio are affected by leverage, we cannot reliably compare these measures across firms with different capital structures.
The same is true for accounting-based performance measures such as return on equity (ROE).
Therefore, most analysts prefer to use performance measures and valuation multiples that are based on the firm’s earnings before interest has been deducted.
Equity Issuances and Dilution
It is sometimes (incorrectly) argued that issuing equity will dilute existing shareholders’ ownership, so debt financing should be used instead.
Suppose Jet Sky Airlines (JSA) currently has no debt and 500 million shares of stock outstanding, which is currently trading at a price of $16.
Last month the firm announced that it would expand and the expansion will require the purchase of $1 billion of new planes, which will be financed by issuing new equity.
Suppose now JSA sells 62.5 million new shares at the current price of 16 per share to raise the additional 1 billion needed to purchase the planes.
Assets | Before | After |
---|---|---|
Cash | 1000 | |
Existing assets | 8000 | 8000 |
Total Value | 8000 | 9000 |
# shares (out) | 500 | 562.5 |
Value per share | 16 | 16 |
Result: share prices don’t change. Any gain or loss associated with the transaction will result from the NPV of the investments the firm makes with the funds raised.
MM is truly about the Conservation of Value Principle in perfect financial markets
Remember to solve:
QUESTIONS?
Henrique C. Martins
[Henrique C. Martins] [henrique.martins@fgv.br] [Teaching Resources] [Practice T/F & Numeric] [Interact][Do not use without permission]